QR-big-box-ad
CLS_bigbox

Hyperinflation and the Government Scare Tactics that use them


“Families Can’t Live Beyond Their Means—Neither Can Governments”

This argument is one of the strongest cases for a fiscal tightening of the belt.  Indeed, why should governments have a different fiscal standard than the nuclear family?

Such arguments however, cloud certain realities, in that families DO take loans out on things, such as education and homes, as well as borrowing for consumption.   And this same dichotomy exists for government spending as well.  When expenditures are made with an investment mindset, it’s a wholly different thing from consumptive borrowing.

So to apply the notion of dual usage of borrowed funds, instead of education and housing, the federal governments’ borrowing can bring about boons in the form of more employment and increased production

“Deficit Spending is Wasteful, Let’s Do Without It”

A counterargument to the aforementioned ‘potential benefits’ of leveraged spending, would point to the ineffectual nature of spending in general and that government intervention simply serves to crowd out private investment driving the economy further away from Pareto optimal economic conditions (Pareto Optimal being, a state where changing any one variable would result in a negative change elsewhere).


In response to that, one should consider Lipsey’s and Lancaster’s Theory of Second Best, where in a market/economy with one or more of the assumed conditions in the General Equilibrium Theory are broken, any attempts to move towards Pareto Optimality will actually be worse off than letting 2 seemingly ‘un-optimal’ factors cancel themselves out.

To Illustrate, take a polluting company which possesses a monopoly and therefore and produces less than it could to maintain high prices.  If there is a move to increase the number of competitors, the level of harm would be increased—simply letting the factor of monopoly offset the problem of externalities (pollution) is a better route in this case.

Drawing on this and applying it to deficits and spending, advocating thrift in an attempt to move towards Pareto Optimality, when the market has severe problems of contracted demand and lending reticence by the banks, will not only NOT guarantee a net benefit but can worsen it, as in the case of the polluting company.

“USA Will be the Next Greece … And Soon”

A popular argument for lifting up fiscal bootstraps involves Greece.  It’s easy to relate Greece’s problems to the US, making forthcoming chaos sound quite possible.  That said, this is a scare tactic.  Propaganda.

And at first glance, the comparison seems true.   Debt comparisons between these 2 countries in terms of the public debt are shown in the table.

In absolute terms, US trounces Greece’s interest payment amount.  As a percentage of GDP though, it is actually a smaller amount, largely owing from the fact the US economy is 40 times larger than Greece (14 trillion versus 302 billion).  However, if one takes a look at total debt, including intergovernmental debt, the ratio to GDP is much closer, with both countries around 100% with Greece sitting at 115% and the US at around 94.27%

Despite the apparent parity, the US debt situation has 2 elements that make it different, as discussed by Robert Green:

 

(1) Greece pays higher interest on its debt than the US

The average coupon interest rate for outstanding US debt (Debt To The Public) is just 2.5% (as of March 31, 2010, according to the Bureau of the Public Debt) and the Fiscal year 2011 budget projects an average interest rate for the fiscal year 2011 of just 2.0%.  Confidence in the US is what primarily allows interest rates demanded to be so low.

(2) Greece cannot finance its debt with the printing of money (double-edged advantage)

If push comes to shove, the US can ‘print’ or finance its debt by buying treasuries, Greece cannot.  Hyperinflation is purported to result from any mass printing of money, however inflation requires there to be a willingness to lend (on the banks’ part) and a willingness to take out loans (on the part of consumers), both elements clearly depressed and missing at the present, in Greece.

If this lack of lending and borrowing vigor persists into the future, hyperinflation would likewise be a case of Chicken Little.  However, predictions of sentiment in the future would be speculating at best, just as it would be to attempt to predict the sharp reverse in the US bond market.

 

These factors illustrate the differences one must take into account between Greece and the US debt.  Objections would include the issue of intergovernmental debt and the point in time where social security payments necessitate the agency to reclaim its lent money.  However, the transition period when such redemptions of bonds aside, this debt owed to itself essentially indicates how a portion of debt is more flexible than public debt.

HYPERINFLATION

Printing Of Money & Hyperinflation Scares

Overzealous doomsayers like to prey on misconceptions about just how close hyperinflation is to becoming reality.  One must note however, that the increase in money supply does not necessitate inflation if that money is not being lent, which means at the minimum, hyperinflation will not arise.  Moreover, there has not been a perfect correlation of inflation and the money supply-this is without taking into account any other variables behind the data.

The reason for the lack of more lockstep interaction could be laden in how M2 money supply is defined.   M2 among other things, such as deposits at banks, includes the holdings of cash outside of banks.  In times of great apprehension on the public’s part, there will be a larger amount of dollars held, representing the atmosphere of pessimism.

This in turn, can slightly increase the M2 figure, but what should be focused on is that the willingness of individuals to spend is depressed.  The final link to this argument is the aforementioned other variable which is the velocity of money (amount of economic activity associated with a given money supply); which is weak due to said pessimism.

 

Zimbabwe

Other arguments one should be wary of are those that bring up the printing of money and the hyperinflation in places like Zimbabwe.  Saying a country will become the next Zimbabwe is hyperbole at best, as Zimbabwe’s hyperinflation is a result of extremely poor rule, which is manifested in its management of the economy.

To avoid this state, a country like the United States would need to do the following: drastically reduce its level of democratization, turn youth groups into paramilitary wings, seize farms and run them into the ground, deter foreign investment by using said paramilitary wings to seize assets and terrorize the populace and commit a host of other counter-intuitive actions before any exaggerated statements can avoid being regarded as a monetary equivalent of Godwin’s law.

Many other instances of hyperinflation such as those pre 1980 were accompanied with the fact that fiat money systems were in place; however this fact was always accompanied with a weak central government and civil/social unrest, including war.

What Should You Take Away From This?

Given that such themes of deficit and hyperinflation doom are less apocalyptic than first observed, investing in commodities (gold included) should not be undertaken with overconfidence.  As well, complete divestment from US bonds and cash is unwarranted.

If you are going to make a bet that commodities will continue to benefit from the economic and social climate, then you should do it with a sound rationale.

An example of a more prudent way of going about commodity investment is to invest in broad based commodity ETFs.  The reasoning for this is because commodities have very low correlations with each other.  In addition, research has shown that if there is any possible long run return, in excess of the risk free rate in commodities, it is achieved by holding a portfolio of equally weighted periodically rebalanced commodity contracts (which Erb and Harvey details in their paper “Tactical and Strategic Value of Long run Commodity Futures”).

The implication for the average investor is this: buy a broad based ETF (which holds portfolios of contracts, so that you the investor can avoid the duty of rollover and rebalancing), if you do not have many other assets like stocks or bonds.  Also, buy ETFs which don’t have many commodities when you have other non-commodity assets to speak of.

In all, besides avoiding the arguments which use hard and absolute statements (which are a red light in terms of fallaciousness), one should also take great care in realizing that economics is not perfect; therefore arguments which depend on what may or may not happen are either individuals’ best guesses and/or estimates.  Regardless, having a more pragmatic approach with your money is never the worst choice.

By Alfred Yim, Staff Writer

In association with:

The ARB Team
Arbitrage Magazine
Business News with BITE

Liked this post? Why not buy the ARB team a beer?
Just click an ad or donate below (thank you!)

 

Liked this article? Hated it? Comment below and share your opinions with other ARB readers!

 

Quantumrun Foresight
Show more